Customize Consent Preferences

We use cookies to help you navigate efficiently and perform certain functions. You will find detailed information about all cookies under each consent category below.

The cookies that are categorized as "Necessary" are stored on your browser as they are essential for enabling the basic functionalities of the site. ... 

Always Active

Necessary cookies are required to enable the basic features of this site, such as providing secure log-in or adjusting your consent preferences. These cookies do not store any personally identifiable data.

No cookies to display.

Functional cookies help perform certain functionalities like sharing the content of the website on social media platforms, collecting feedback, and other third-party features.

No cookies to display.

Analytical cookies are used to understand how visitors interact with the website. These cookies help provide information on metrics such as the number of visitors, bounce rate, traffic source, etc.

No cookies to display.

Performance cookies are used to understand and analyze the key performance indexes of the website which helps in delivering a better user experience for the visitors.

No cookies to display.

Advertisement cookies are used to provide visitors with customized advertisements based on the pages you visited previously and to analyze the effectiveness of the ad campaigns.

No cookies to display.

Loading...
Most Recent Stories

Richard Werner Explains Our Money

There’s a clash of ideas in Richard Werner’s work and that of Monetary Realism’s.  I’ve had a stack of papers on my desk here by Werner, a German economist, that I’ve been meaning to write posts about for weeks.  But they’re so good that I don’t to do them injustice.  But then today I am clicking through my FT links and I see this:

“There are different types of money. The first is legal tender paper money. This is mainly used by the public for petty transactions and amounts to only about 3 per cent of the total money supply. Another type of money also created by the central bank is solely for the use of its clients, the banks. This is reserve money. It stays in the banks’ accounts at the BoE to settle their claims against each other. If one bank reduces its reserves, this raises those of another bank, leaving the total amount of this closed-loop money unchanged. It normally also amounts to about 3 per cent of the money supply, but it never circulates in the economy and as such is not really money. So what about the money that is used for most transactions and accounts for the bulk of the actual money supply?

As Martin Wolf has pointed out, it is created by profit-oriented companies, the banks, when they do what is commonly referred to as “lending money”. But they don’t lend existing money. Instead, they newly invent the money that they lend…”

That’s perfect.  MR describes the money types as outside money and inside money.  That is, inside money is the money that’s created inside the private sector by banks (bank deposits).  And outside money is the money created by the government outside the private sector.  As Werner notes, the money that matters most is inside money.  Outside money just facilitates the use of inside money (for instance, cash allows withdrawal of money for someone who has an inside money account and reserves or central bank money simply help settle interbank payments and smooth the efficiency of the payments system).

Anyhow, he has some other thoughts on having the government borrow directly from the banks, but that’s the policy side of things.  Me, I am more interested in getting the operational description exactly right and Werner seems to really get it.

 

Comments are closed.