Customize Consent Preferences

We use cookies to help you navigate efficiently and perform certain functions. You will find detailed information about all cookies under each consent category below.

The cookies that are categorized as "Necessary" are stored on your browser as they are essential for enabling the basic functionalities of the site. ... 

Always Active

Necessary cookies are required to enable the basic features of this site, such as providing secure log-in or adjusting your consent preferences. These cookies do not store any personally identifiable data.

No cookies to display.

Functional cookies help perform certain functionalities like sharing the content of the website on social media platforms, collecting feedback, and other third-party features.

No cookies to display.

Analytical cookies are used to understand how visitors interact with the website. These cookies help provide information on metrics such as the number of visitors, bounce rate, traffic source, etc.

No cookies to display.

Performance cookies are used to understand and analyze the key performance indexes of the website which helps in delivering a better user experience for the visitors.

No cookies to display.

Advertisement cookies are used to provide visitors with customized advertisements based on the pages you visited previously and to analyze the effectiveness of the ad campaigns.

No cookies to display.

Loading...
Most Recent Stories

BOE Research: QE Works Best When Markets are Under Duress

When you study QE you really need to account for how it’s implemented and in what environment it’s implemented.  I’ve long stated that QE1 was probably much more effective than QE2 and QE3 because it was enacted during a period when markets were anything but “normal”.  Therefore, the central bank’s intervention as a market maker had a significantly positive impact on the broader economy.   This is a conclusion that the Bank of England’s researchers agrees with in a recent bit of research:

“We have developed a simple and highly stylized model of the economy to assess whether shifts in the balance sheet of the central bank have a significant impact on real variables. Analytical solutions to that model are not, in general, available. So we turn to simulations of a calibrated version of this OLG model. We find that across a fairly wide set of environments – with different rules for the setting of interest rates and different ways in which fiscal policy is conducted – the  impact of asset purchases working through a portfolio re-balancing channel is weak or absent.  Because our periods are long, one could interpret this result as showing that the central bank swapping shorter-dated bonds for longer-dated bonds is relatively ineffective, at least when financial markets are operating normally.

That result does not show that central bank asset purchases (quantitative easing) do not work. And it certainly does not show that the major expansion of the balance sheets of the central banks in the US, UK, Japan and in the euro zone in recent years have been ineffective.   We reach a different conclusion, which is that the main way in which such balance sheet changes have worked is probably not through the operation of a portfolio rebalancing of private sector portfolios undertaken in an environment of normally functioning financial markets.  But LSAPs undertaken in an environment when financial markets are not working normally may well have significant effects. “

That makes sense.  In a normal environment swapping a t-bond or MBS for reserves/deposits doesn’t make a huge impact on the economy.  On the other hand, if you implement this swap during a period when various assets are significantly undervalued or under duress then the rebalancing effect can have a significant impact on broader assets and portfolios.

See also: Understanding Quantitative Easing

Comments are closed.